The Fine Line Between Simplification and Deregulation

03/07/2025
Europe must tackle its "internal tariffs" in response to Trump’s protectionism, but carefully
Number: 246
Year: 2025
Author(s): Marco Buti, Marcello Messori

Europe must tackle its "internal tariffs" in response to Trump’s protectionism, but carefully. A commentary by Marco Buti, and Marcello Messori

deregulation

The Trump administration’s protectionist measures have brought renewed attention to what Mario Draghi referred to, citing an IMF study, as the European Union’s "internal tariffs." Italy’s Prime Minister Giorgia Meloni has argued that European institutions must reduce these barriers to counterbalance U.S. tariffs.

However, these internal barriers stem predominantly from divergent national policies that obstruct the functioning of the EU single market, leading to numerous infringement procedures against member states—Italy alone currently faces 65 pending cases.

While removing these internal barriers largely falls within national governments' responsibilities, the simplification of EU regulations is a separate yet equally critical challenge. Simplification has featured prominently in reports by Mario Draghi and Enrico Letta, and more recently, in the European Commission's "Competitiveness Compass," through its Omnibus packages aimed at easing administrative burdens for businesses.

The need for simplification is pressing, as the EU must urgently modernize its outdated production models and support the development of efficient small and medium-sized enterprises (SMEs).

Effective regulation, rather than representing an economic and social cost, is in fact a strategic competitive advantage internationally.

Crucially, simplification must never be confused with deregulation: deregulation implies abandoning key policy objectives—most notably, in the EU’s case, green transition and social inclusion. Simplification, by contrast, enhances regulatory efficiency, pursuing the same objectives at lower costs and with higher positive externalities.

Although subtle in practice, this distinction is pivotal if the EU is to combine innovation and competitiveness with environmental and social sustainability in the face of external pressures from Trump's policies.

Yet regulatory complexity often arises not from the Commission's original proposals, but from cumbersome negotiations and uncoordinated amendments introduced by the Council, European Parliament, and later, national legislators. Additionally, essential institutions for effective simplification—such as the Competitiveness Council or Ecofin in matters like the Green Deal—are frequently inadequately engaged.

Moreover, regulation often lags behind innovation, resulting in overly formalistic, self-referential implementation practices. This issue is compounded by fragmented national supervisory approaches and enforcement actions, as seen with institutions like the European Financial Reporting Advisory Group (EFRAG).

So, how can the EU simplify regulations without sliding into deregulation? Four measures provide a solid starting point.

First, given the complexity that typically arises during negotiations between the Council and the Parliament, approval processes should include binding impact assessments of amendments to ensure they do not excessively complicate original proposals or burden economic activity. Entrusting these assessments to independent bodies would further mitigate risks of regulatory capture by vested interests.

Second, EU directives often undergo significant distortion during national implementation, with additional obligations (gold-plating) that surpass necessary national adaptations. Therefore, prioritizing self-executing regulations over directives would streamline regulatory processes.

Third, as a key member of EFRAG, the Commission should ensure European sustainability standards align closely with international benchmarks (promoted by the IFRS), unless clearly justified deviations are necessary.

Finally, enforcement actions against violations of single-market rules should be centralized to overcome national fragmentation. For example, the European financial markets should fall under a single supervisory authority—such as a reformed European Securities and Markets Authority (ESMA)—rather than 27 national bodies.

Each measure involves trade-offs. Self-executing regulations, for instance, require more detailed EU provisions, while impact assessments for amendments can lengthen adoption times.

Ultimately, the EU must avoid the illusion of crafting "complete contracts," weighed down by redundant oversight. Instead, it should adopt "incomplete contracts" incentivized through centralized mechanisms—including financial ones—that effectively ensure regulatory compliance.

A version of this article originally appeared in Il Sole 24 Ore.

IEP@BU does not express opinions of its own. The opinions expressed in this publication are those of the authors. Any errors or omissions are the responsibility of the authors.

If you want to stay up-to-date with the initiative of the Institute for European Policymaking@Bocconi University, subscribe to our monthly NEWSLETTER here.